Friday, 17 May 2024

NCEI versus PSR compared

For many years I have studied on and off the NOAA US divisional statistics of temperature and precipitation, because climate statistics — like all statistics — are always interesting to me if at times capable of making me very angry when runaway climate change is shown.

What is interesting is that NOAA has two sets of precipitation (and temperature) sets for each of the contiguous US states. One is published by the National Center for Environmental Information and the other by the Physical Sciences Laboratory. Over the period I have used them to study climate, I have assumed the two to be essentially completely interchangeable for the purpose of statistical tables, although for graphical purposes I can prefer one or the other (I prefer NCEI for precipitation maps and PSL for temperature maps) depending on the precise maps offered.

When I realised NCEI was offering comparisons for all months, I decided to try to look at each continental state (this excludes Hawaii) and tabulate its wettest and driest month since record began. However, when I tried to do this on the PSL site, I found that there appeared to be some differences between the two. To test this, I tabulated the wettest and driest months for all states east of the Continental Divide. For states west of the Divide there are generally sufficient months with zero or negligible precipitation that I decided only to tabulate each state’s wettest month. I have included both sets of units for convenience of readers not familiar with US units.

State Wettest month Driest month (omitted for states west of Divide)
NCEI PSL NCEI PSL
Month in mm Month in mm Month in mm Month in mm
Alabama July 1916 17.59 446.8 July 1916 18.13 460.5 October 1963 0.03 0.8 October 1963 0.03 0.8
Alaska September 1925 7.59 192.8 February 1979 0.72 18.3
Arizona January 1993 5.22 132.6 January 1993 5.72 145.3
Arkansas October 2009 14.13 358.9 October 2009 13.38 339.9 October 1963 0.13 3.3 October 1963 0.18 4.6
California January 1995 12.50 317.5 January 1909 13.50 342.9
Colorado April 1900 5.45 138.4 April 1900 5.13 130.3 November 1904 0.03 0.8 November 1904 0.03 0.8
Connecticut October 2005 15.92 404.4 October 2005 16.02 406.9 March 1915 0.28 7.1 March 1915 0.27 6.9
Delaware August 1967 12.58 319.5 September 1935 11.50 292.1 October 1963 0.12 3.0 October 1963 0.13 3.3
Florida August 1898 13.49 342.6 September 2004 14.25 362.0 November 2016 0.21 5.3 October 1940 0.16 4.1
November 2016
Georgia July 1916 13.46 341.9 July 1916 14.06 357.1 October 1963 0.06 1.5 October 1963 0.04 1.0
Idaho December 1964 8.52 216.4 December 1964 6.72 170.7
Illinois September 1926 9.62 244.3 September 1926 10.18 258.6 October 1964 0.18 4.6 October 1964 0.15 3.8
Indiana January 1950 10.11 256.8 January 1950 10.01 254.3 March 1910 0.21 5.3 March 1910 0.22 5.6
Iowa July 1993 10.45 265.4 July 1993 10.75 273.1 October 1952 0.02 0.5 October 1952 0.02 0.5
Kansas May 2019 10.51 267.0 May 2019 10.22 259.6 January 1986 0.00 0.0 January 1986 0.00 0.0
November 1989 0.00 0.0 November 1989 0.00 0.0
Kentucky January 1937 15.16 385.1 January 1937 15.49 393.4 October 1963 0.14 3.6 October 1963 0.14 3.6
Louisiana May 1907 15.09 383.3 October 2009 16.41 416.8 October 1952 0.03 0.8 October 1952 0.03 0.8
Maine October 2005 11.26 286.0 October 2005 12.62 320.5 March 1915 0.46 11.7 October 1947 0.37 9.4
Maryland August 1955 11.85 301.0 July 1945 12.68 322.1 October 1963 0.15 3.8 October 2000 0.12 3.0
Massachusetts October 2005 14.03 356.4 October 2005 13.99 355.3 March 1915 0.09 2.3 March 1915 0.11 2.8
Michigan September 1986 8.72 221.5 June 1943 7.22 183.4 March 1910 0.26 6.6 March 1910 0.22 5.6
Minnesota June 2014 8.07 205.0 June 2014 8.13 206.5 December 1913 0.07 1.8 December 1913 0.06 1.5
Mississippi April 1991 14.36 364.7 December 1982 15.62 396.7 October 1963 0.07 1.8 October 1963 0.05 1.3
Missouri September 1993 11.31 287.3 June 1928 11.69 296.9 January 1986 0.10 2.5 January 1986 0.21 5.3
Montana June 1944 6.38 162.1 June 1944 6.40 162.6 October 1987 0.11 2.8 October 1987 0.12 3.0
Nebraska June 1967 8.20 208.3 June 1967 8.64 219.5 November 1914 0.01 0.3 November 1914 0.01 0.3
November 1939 0.01 0.3
Nevada January 1916 3.65 92.7 January 1916 3.63 92.2
New Hampshire October 2005 13.65 346.7 October 2005 13.23 336.0 March 1915 0.19 4.8 March 1915 0.22 5.6
New Jersey August 2011 15.67 398.0 August 2011 15.79 401.1 October 1963 0.25 6.4 October 1963 0.25 6.4
New Mexico September 1941 5.48 139.2 July 1911 4.60 116.8
New York June 1972 8.58 217.9 October 2005 9.38 238.3 October 1963 0.34 8.6 October 1963 0.41 10.4
North Carolina September 1999 13.22 335.8 August 1901 13.00 330.2 October 2000 0.08 2.0 October 2000 0.06 1.5
North Dakota July 1993 7.97 202.4 July 1993 8.11 206.0 November 1939 0.03 0.8 November 1939 0.03 0.8
Ohio January 1937 9.69 246.1 January 1937 9.42 239.3 October 1963 0.23 5.8 October 1963 0.24 6.1
Oklahoma May 2015 14.44 366.8 May 2015 14.40 365.8 January 1986 0.03 0.8 January 1986 0.04 1.0
Oregon December 1964 13.05 331.5 December 1964 16.33 414.8
Pennsylvania June 1972 11.22 285.0 June 1972 11.63 295.4 October 1963 0.16 4.1 October 1963 0.22 5.6
Rhode Island March 2010 14.75 374.7 March 2010 14.76 374.9 March 1915 0.14 3.6 March 1915 0.14 3.6
South Carolina July 1916 14.41 366.0 August 1901 23.60 599.4 October 2000 0.02 0.5 October 2000 0.07 1.8
South Dakota May 1962 6.78 172.2 May 1962 6.88 174.8 November 1939 0.01 0.3 November 1939 0.01 0.3
Tennessee January 1937 14.53 369.1 January 1937 13.41 340.6 October 1963 0.03 0.8 October 1963 0.03 0.8
Texas May 2015 9.05 229.9 May 2015 11.15 283.2 October 1952 0.03 0.8 October 1952 0.02 0.5
Utah October 1972 3.69 93.7 October 2004 4.10 104.1
Vermont November 1927 10.61 269.5 November 1927 10.48 266.2 March 1915 0.32 8.1 March 1915 0.35 8.9
Virginia September 1999 13.84 351.5 September 1999 10.37 263.4 October 2000 0.09 2.3 October 2000 0.03 0.8
Washington December 1933 16.61 421.9 December 1933 24.36 618.7
West Virginia November 1985 9.53 242.1 September 2018 9.48 240.8 October 1963 0.24 6.1 October 1963 0.23 5.8
Wisconsin September 1986 8.38 212.9 September 1986 8.43 214.1 February 1958 0.11 2.8 February 1969 0.10 2.5
February 1969 0.11 2.8
Wyoming May 1908 5.09 129.3 May 1908 5.83 148.1 November 1939 0.02 0.5 November 1939 0.02 0.5
If we look closely, we see that there are a few cases where NCEI and PSR do differ substantially (shaded in red). Almost all of these are for states’ wettest months — the driest months vary less between the two sets and there are many fewer months listed even comparing only the states east of the Divide.

In the cases of Washington state and Idaho, whilst the identity of the state’s wettest-ever month is definite, the estimated actual amount of precipitation varies by as much as a quarter.

In the cases of California and West Virginia, the precipitation figures for the state’s two wettest months are very nearly equal and which is the wettest may not be perfectly clear.

The reason for these discrepancies if not perfectly clear. In the late 2000s, state precipitation measurements were significantly updated to take into account much higher precipitation at high altitudes (similar updates occurred for Tasmania in Australia, and for the United Kingdom). Differences in this update for mountainous regions may be important, but a variety of other factors like:
  1. difficulties measuring tropical cyclone rainfall in the South Atlantic States and New York
  2. difficulties measuring lake-effect precipitation in Michigan
may also be important explaining the observed differences. I have not yet researched possible causes of the differences between NCEI and PSL, but still find it interesting to note that they exist.

Saturday, 4 May 2024

Racism, labour supply shocks and the contrasting responses of the US and South Africa

In last year’s Shocking Contrasts: Political Responses to Exogenous Supply Shocks, Ron Rogowski discussed a number of supply shocks to land, labour and human capital. Here I noted that he never discussed a case involving exogenous gain of land, nor of loss or gain of physical capital. My older post was itself about the effects of sudden gain of land, and I do wish to discuss the physical capital issue, but will do so later. More interesting is that, whilst Rogowski discusses loss of labour through high mortality and loss of land via declining trade he never discusses loss of labour in a land-rich society through the latter mechanism. I have noted that this could have profound effects before here and here. For a labour-scarce twentieth-century nation, complete loss of access to the abundant labour of Europe and monsoon Asia would have created a much larger supply shock than the Black Death. Even in the populous United States, it would have amounted to a labour supply cut of 95 percent by a crude calculation, and elsewhere it would have been larger still. Complete loss of access to the labour of Europe and monsoon Asia would have totally upended the racial hierarchies of the US and South Africa. Oppressed black populations would have used skyrocketing wages from a decimated effective labour supply (noted in the first paragraph) to demand political and economic rights, whilst the wealthy would have been literally crippled because of:

  • limited latitude to substitute for labour due to already having done so substantially due to labour’s scarcity
  • risk of further retaliation from abroad if the ruling classes tried to further restrict black mobility or wages
  • risk of disloyalty from their poor white supporters if they attempted a military solution
    • this was a major factor behind Goldwater’s 1964 landslide loss, as many racially conservative whites refused to risk his Vietnam policies involving possible nuclear strikes

Shocking Contrasts never uses Southern Africa’s loss of access to the highly abundant labour of South Asia as an example of a supply shock. In communication with me Rogowski argued that it was endogenous and anticipated, but I question his argument. Before Indian independence similar if less severe racial policies had no effect. South Africa thus gained unlimited access via trade to labour-intensive products from South Asia. Hence, even if incoming Prime Minister François Daniel Malan and his advisers knew changes were likely when South Asia became independent, they would have not assumed major consequences.

The United States had similar laws of racial discrimination that effectively excluded African–Americans from voting or from living in virtually any rural or suburban area outside the plantation South, despite constitutional amendments aimed at creating such rights. Expanding trade after 1870 weakened the economic position of black Americans and increased the determination of whites to eliminate theoretical constitutional rights. The position of black Americans steadily deteriorated and — as had been noted by many commentators from Walter Dean Burnham to Frances Fox Piven and would occur again after 1973 — political influence was monopolised by the rich while poorer whites voted in smaller and smaller numbers. (Not discussing why this happened at the very time political participation in Europe was rising and suffrage expanding was a major omission from Commerce and Coalitions, although the contrast is precisely analogous to Eastern Europe versus Western Europe in the long sixteenth century discussed on pages 157 and 158.)

Mass influence upon policy in trade-open labour-scarce (as the US and South Africa are) economies is exceedingly unlikely for the simple reason that free trade eliminates requisite economic power for all except minimally the top decile and perhaps an even smaller elite. Nonetheless, neither:

  1. those who acknowledge that mass interest groups have zero influence upon US government policy and that this state of affairs has been maintained since the 1973 oil crisis, nor
  2. writers like Rogowski of David Lektzian and Dennis Patterson (who in the 2000s analysed theoretical practical effects of sanctions on countries with varying factor abundances)
seriously consider extremely plausible arguments that:
  1. mass influence on politics in trade-open labour-scarce economies is generally implausible
  2. the most probable political models for a trade-open labour-scarce society are the family business monarchy of the Gulf States or the semi-family dictatorships of the East Slavic and Turkic “core USSR”
  3. only collapse of global trade could potentially produce anything resembling democratisation of such societies

By the 1940s, the US ruling class was acquainted with the spectre of widespread worker revolution in Europe. If successful, US capitalists would have been placed in direct conflict with workers’ states dedicated at least theoretically to their expropriation, and likely to redirecting exports away from the US. Another threat, already developed to some extent during the interwar period, was restriction of foreign access to the products of abundant local labour by bourgeois nationalists who wanted independent local development.

The US ruling class understood it had to compromise with Europe and newly independent Asian nations to expand trade. However, given that it gained immense profits by oppressing blacks, it never assumed that greater rights and opportunities for the mass of African-Americans would remain permanent. US policies between Smith v. Allwright and the 1973 oil crisis were contradictory because of conflicting needs to appease European workers and nonwhite nations versus maximising the profits and power of the rich. Rogowski notes that black leaders did not pursue the protectionist (or anti-IMF and anti-GATT) policies that would have immensely benefitted the mass of African-Americans, and their reliance on a federal government with conflicting needs is almost certainly the reason. Once the 1973 oil crisis established an alternative rentier-state model that made tax revolts by the super-rich easier and more rewarding, the US ruling class could establish a much more consistent policy of reversing civil rights gains, lowering or eliminating taxes on the rich, and completely eliminating the influence of mass interest groups (the bottom ninety percent) on government policy.

Unlike the US ruling class and perhaps even its white supporters, the National Party of South Africa and its Boer supporters undoubtedly came out of the war with no understanding of either the newly independent nations of Asia or the newly aligned nations of the Soviet bloc. Consequently, South Africa would be exposed to the labour supply shock that the US ruling class avoided. Its black population could therefore fight a longer and more effective struggle against apartheid. Unlike Jim Crow, apartheid would be completely destroyed, and with it South Africa‘s white ruling elite.

One might think the difference resulted from the much greater resources of the US ruling class, which gave it more access to information about global geopolitics. However, even under apartheid South Africa was not isolated from geopolitics and was relied on to restrain Stalinism in Africa. Moreover, Jan Smuts, Malan’s long-time predecessor, had played a key role in establishing the League of Nations, placing even more doubt that South African elites were that ignorant. Another critical difference might be that the most insular (and racially intolerant) regions of the United States — the Deep South, the Great Basin and the Plains — were virtually unrepresented amongst the postwar political and judicial elite. Thus, the most likely reason for the difference is that the US ruling class was much more acquainted with the threat of Communism and thus invested in short-term domestic compromises to help defeat it.