In my first post reviewing Ron Rogowski’s Commerce and Coalitions, I said I would discuss the numerous issues raised by capital-rich, land-rich and labour-poor economies. Since the book was originally published, the effect of these problems has undoubtedly been multiplied: many of the problematic political and social trends since the 1973 oil crisis can easily be understood in terms of the expected political behaviour of economies rich in capital and land, but poor in labour, under a condition of rapidly expanding trade. This behaviour is, at first sight, contradictory when compared to other economies, but understandable in terms of their basic endowments and structures.
In my review of Commerce and Coalitions, and my communication with Rogowski via email, I noted the absence of capital- and land-rich, labour-poor regions for long periods (in fact for millennia), and that no explanation was given in the book, as if this extremely prolonged absence was accidental and inexplicable.
Why Were Capital- and Land-Rich, Labour-Poor Economies Nonexistent for So Long?
The most significant thing about societies abundant in capital and land but poor in labour is that for almost nineteen centuries at a minimum they were completely nonexistent. Although Rogowski notes that one area in Classical Greece — Miletus, comprising present-day Western Anatolia — was rich in both capital and land, his studies of both the contracting trade of the declining Roman Empire and the expanding trade of the long sixteenth century reveal no region abundant in both capital and land but poor in labour. Rogowski is definite about the lack of capital- and land-rich regions not merely during the long sixteenth century, but until the beginning of the twentieth century. His analysis of the declining Roman Empire is less conclusive but provides no evidence for any region rich in both capital and land.Where The Powerful Are The Rebellious
The counterintuitive, but critical, feature of an economy rich in capital and land, but poor in labour, is that under expanding trade, it is the powerful who rebel. This is because owners of capital and land can then use their ownership of agricultural products, minerals and capital-intensive manufactures to gain economic power in the world market. “Rebellion of the powerful” was noted in American politics as early as Kevin P. Phillips’ 1969 The Emerging Republican Majority, which argued that Richard Nixon’s 1968 election victory was produced by a rebellion by rural and suburban white America against government-enforced civil rights for blacks. Phillips ignored the role of America’s capitalist class in producing GOP dominance at a presidential level from 1968, while his Obama-era preface ignored the 1994 Republican Revolution entirely. Nonetheless, Phillips does demonstrate how American politics has been dominated by rebellions of the powerful — Southern, Plains and Mountain landowners, and since the 1970s, capitalists. With each new generation of Republicans the demands of richest one percent, even the richest 0.01 percent, for elimination of potential balances of power become ever-more extreme. Current GOP ideology originated from Murray Newton Rothbard and James McGill Buchanan. During the 1960s and 1970s these two, in exact opposition to Marx, saw capitalists as “makers” and the majority as “takers”. Their de facto argument was:- the only legitimate state was a privately owned state that gained all income via earning money
- this method is primarily used today by the Gulf oil monarchies
- its impossibility in resource-impoverished Europe and East Asia — where marketable natural resources have been destroyed by glaciation and orogeny — undoubtedly played a key role in those regions’ political development
- taxation was, ipso facto, theft from the “makers”
- public debt (following the classification of states on page 18 of ‘The Politics of the Invisible: Offshore Finance and State Power’) was also ipso facto theft from the makers because it devalued their saved wealth
- legitimising absolute monarchy as divinely ordained (until Rerum Novarum orthodox Christianity held similar views) and making capitalists part of the ruling families
- declaring that God’s laws are divine and cannot be challenged by the masses and a theocracy or caliphate as the only legitimate government
Split Labour Markets and “Labour Imperialism”
In the middle 1970s, University of California Riverside professor of Sociology and Ethnic Studies Edna Bonacich argued in ‘Advanced Capitalism and Black/White Race Relations in the United States: A Split Labor Market Interpretation’, and ‘Abolition, the Extension of Slavery, and the Position of Free Blacks: A Study of Split Labor Markets in the United States, 1830-1863’ that the United States has been always characterised by a “split labour market” based upon wage differentials between blacks and whites and formal or informal rules to hire blacks last and fire them first. This is an extremely efficient means for controlling scarce labour because it pits nonelites against each other. Under expanding trade the scarcity of labour means labour-intensive tradable industries are moved to labour-rich regions and nonelites work only in nontradable industries. Jacobin noted in November 2019 that nontradable industries possess very limited power to produce class solidarity. This would be multiply so when capital neither loses from trade nor needs compromises with labour.- they cannot obtain citizenship:
- de jure for non-Muslims in at least the majority of GCC states
- de facto for almost all non-Arab Muslims and the majority of Arab Muslims
- they are forbidden from forming organisations to represent their interests
- they can be fired at will by citizen employers
- they can never own capital and usually cannot own land
- the United States and Central America plus the non-Stalinist Caribbean
- Australia and noncontinental Oceania
- Russia and Kazakhstan with the labor-supply nations of Tajikistan and the Caucasus
Misconceptions from Absence
There are certain popular theories — even amongst scholars — which may be unconsciously based upon situations where societies abundant in capital and land, but poor in labour, were nonexistent or almost so.1. Development Produces Democratisation
The first theorem that shows a lack of understanding of societies rich in capital and land is that a developed society will always be at least partially democratic, stated by such writers as Robert Dahl and James A. Robinson. This assumption is, upon analysis, clearly based on the assumption that “developed” societies are labour-rich, which was consistently true between the birth of Christ and the end of the nineteenth century. Under this scenario, workers gained alongside capital in the most developed and powerful nations through a democratisation based upon challenges to the landowning class. Due to their opposed positions on trade, capitalists in advanced nations could not consistently ally with landowners to defeat the demands of labour for democracy. Even in nations rich in land but poor in capital and labour, the inability of capital and land to ally strongly meant that democratisation was frequently possible.- colonising internal and external labour sources over which capital and land have unlimited control
- expanding the power of capital sufficiently to disenfranchise labour either de jure or de facto
- privatising the functions of government so that the actual workers have no say in how they are carried out
“with sufficient time, education, and money to get involved in politics”
- high turnout of eligible voters before capital became abundant
- rapidly decreasing turnout amongst the lower classes as the coalition of capital and land made voting more difficult after about 1900
- moderate increases in turnout between the New Deal and the 1973 oil crisis
- falling turnout with mass incarceration and increasing disfranchisement since the middle 1970s
2. Isolation Produces Social Reaction
Closely related to (1) immediately above is the idea that an isolated society is necessarily backward. Whilst this point is much hard to establish than the first, there is enough evidence to question this assumption as reflecting the absence of capital- and land-rich societies during such periods as the declining Roman Empire. Although Rogowski is less clear about the relative abundances of capital, land and labour there, he provides zero evidence that any region of the declining Roman Empire was relatively abundant in both capital and land. This may account for the strength of religion in the ensuing Middle Ages. With no region where only labour benefitted from collapsing trade, political liberation by democratisation, secularisation, and a more scientific approach, which would if strictly applied help the masses, was disfavoured everywhere during the reduced trade of the Middle Ages.3. Underestimated Ruling Class Militancy
Another, more significant, effect of the absence of economies rich in both capital and land is the assumption that the ruling class can never be as militant as the working class. However, the radical capitalism of the modern GOP and the militant Islam supported by the Gulf States are extremely militant movements with undoubted ruling class bases, as is the movement for reconquest of Ukraine in Russia, and Pan-Turkism in Central Asia. Rogowski can be faulted for assuming that under expanding trade, ruling classes in advanced nations with high land:labour ratios will simply be content with corporatisation and severe weakening or elimination of unions. In fact, since the 1973 oil crisis the global ruling class has sought to entirely eliminate the freedom of workers, seen in “noncompete” agreements between corporations that virtually eliminate the freedom of many US workers to seek alternative employment, and prevent them, as The Politically Incorrect Guide to Capitalism wrongly assumed, from choosing employers based upon wage.- even more vulnerable to exploitation by the super-rich, or
- totally dependent on the super-rich and forbidden from criticising them
Any such system would undoubtedly be exceptionally oppressive for an immense majority, who would lose the most basic freedoms.
4. Imperialism Comes from Resource Scarcity
It is typically assumed that Western Europe’s incentive to seek colonies in the tropics and North America resulted from that region’s extreme scarcity of land and mineral resources — in turn due to:
- intensive and repeated Quaternary glaciation producing soils of geologically vanishingly rare fertility
- highly dense rural populations supported by those soils and a highly favourable climate for agriculture
- extreme poverty in metallic minerals, which the glaciers largely destroyed
It is typically argued that natural-resource-poor countries are not worth colonizing, for instance Irma Adelman and Nobuhiko Fuwa in ‘Income Inequality and Development. The 1970s and 1980s Compared’. Except where natural-resource-poor lands possess strategic value, this was true for colonisation by Western Europe. This explains why some of the world’s most natural-resource-poor countries, for example Japan and Nepal, were never colonised.
However, if an imperialist country is labour-poor, it will want primarily to control labour-rich countries. Nevertheless, direct colonial rule is improbable because backward, labour-rich countries that have not experienced revolutions led by workers or landless peasants will inevitably possess indigenous ruling classes too weak to act independently of the ruling classes of the advanced, land-rich nations, and too fearful of potential political threats from their lower classes under expanding trade to avoid such alliances. This relationship, it must be emphasised, is colonialism and is imperialism. The advanced, land-rich societies exploit abundant labour, pay this labour vastly less than its productivity, and dictate the politics of the source nations. Although significant local income sources, remittances from the Gulf, North America, Russia, Kazakhstan and Australia are very small vis-à-vis corporate profits.
Similarly, foreign aid emerged with the transfer of global power to the land-rich US and USSR. Aid can be understood as a means of maintaining friendly regimes and consequently access to abundant labour. As Gilens and Page noted in Affluence and Influence, mass interest groups have zero independent political influence even in the purportedly democratic US; however, loss of access to the abundant labour of humid Eurasia would likely empower these mass interest groups radically and rapidly. In other countries rich in both capital and land, loss of this access would likely produce much more violent mass [citizen] rebellions, although, because so many of these societies are so specialised that they do not engage in manufacturing at all, democratisation even under these conditions remains uncertain.
No comments:
Post a Comment