Monday, 25 August 2025

A book that rivals ‘Foot Ball’

Today, looking to correct a YouTube comment, I stumbled upon a book that at first was curious to me but when I open a small sample I realised immediately that I had stumbled upon a book as bad as R. Picken’s awful Foot Ball of many years ago.

Written by one Larry Robinson and originally published in 2020, the book is titled “The Myth of the Moderate Democrat: How the Party of Jacksonian Democracy transitioned to Marxist Statist Collectivism”. Its author claims to have been a political junkie for six decades before the publication of The Myth of the Moderate Democrat, and to be a pastor, evangelist and theologian possessing a Doctor of Divinity.

What Robinson said in the section of the book that was accessible is at first familiar Republican propaganda — that FDR governed with a Marxist ideology. Whilst there may have been Communist sympathisers in American government during the New Deal era, the reality is that the New Deal was a series of largely ineffective compromises involving many players not only within the United States. As Ron Rogowski in his Commerce and Coalitions and Jeffrey Williamson and Peter Lindert in American Inequality: A Macroeconomic History demonstrate, the New Deal was a by-product of a series of revolutions and hyperinflations that affected Europe after post-World War I chaos whereby Europe’s working classes supported the Bolshevik Revolution but failed to spread it beyond the Russian Empire. The result of all these processes was a prolonged “deglobalisation” that lasted until the rise of the oil monarchies in the middle 1970s, while the result of deglobalisation in capital- and land-rich nations [North America, continental Oceania] was a pronounced, but historically unique reduction in income inequality. 

FDR was never a Marxist. In fact, as Thomas Paul Bonflglio noted in his 2012 The Psychopathology of American Capitalism, the New Deal was accompanied by a dismantling of the left-leaning parties of the first third of the century. Especially in the nonplantation South and some Western states settled therefrom [e.g. Nebraska], ballot laws became so rigid that formerly not insignificant “socialist” parties could never even access the ballot. As Bonfiglio noted, this placed American politics, especially after the war, in a unique position whereby “left” meant what most would consider right-wing, and anything remotely centrist was called “far left”, which has always made me laugh. Also, unlike the social liberalism of the European working classes, who supported legalisation of homosexuality in the 1920s or earlier, the New Deal was socially highly conservative, involving a uniquely strict “Motion Picture Production Code”. Following the collapse of the union base beginning in the 1960s, the Democrats did reverse themselves vis-à-vis the New Deal in order to stay viable. However, this made the 1990 to 2020 Democratic Party one of strong social liberalism combined with — by the standards of the rest of the world — strong economic conservatism. Today, demography and the desire of the global ruling classes to overcome the (high but insufficient) ceiling social liberalism places on corporate profits is, if the World Socialist Web Site’s [originally New York Times’] assessment of declining Democratic membership and registration be accurate, likely to make the Democratic Party less and less viable with time.

Robinson does not understand that Democrats completely abandoned collectivism after the 1980s, and their embrace of social liberalism in the 1960s is evidence they were abandoning it then. By the 1990s the difference between the parties became exclusively social rather than economic, because the hegemony of big business as donors absolutely excludes any party representing the bottom nine-tenth or more of America’s economic distribution. Demography, in this situation, defeats liberalism because the socially liberal tend to have extremely few if any children, which explains the present takeover of the radical right at a global level.

Monday, 11 August 2025

How public is a US “public university”?

A couple of weeks ago, I read an article that I subsequently had trouble recovering a second time on Google Scholar — despite its usefulness to me on Wikipedia. The article, titled ‘Ideological Voting Applied to the School Desegregation Cases in the Federal Courts of Appeals from the 1960s and 1970s’, is an interesting look at how circuit courts dealt with the questions arising after Brown v. Board of Education outlawed de jure segregation. Whilst the article’s results are mostly — though not all — familiar, it makes an interesting comment that is still remarkably familiar:
“i. Law School Education

There has been a common criticism by conservatives that the federal judiciary is comprised of liberal activists from elite Ivy League law schools. In the Fifth Circuit, justices serving in the 1960s and early 1970s attended several different law schools. Fifteen justices represent the Fifth Circuit... and only three of those judges attended Ivy League schools: John Cooper Godbold, Irving Goldberg, and Elbert Tuttle. Interestingly, these three judges do meet the common conservative argument noted above. All three judges held an impressive liberal voting record (eleven to one) on school desegregation panel”
At the same time, it has been a pertinent observation that since Charles Evans Whittaker in 1957, no jurist who obtained his or her law degree from a public law school has been nominated to the Supreme Court of the United States. [To be precise, the last twenty-six confirmed candidates, and last thirty nominees, all gained their legal education from private law schools]. Given my familiarity with arguments like those of Red Flag and Robert Ovetz, and the shift of US politics to the right since the 1966 midterm elections and the expansion of trade beginning slightly earlier, one should theoretically be unsurprised by the disappearance of public law school educations from SCOTUS. However, it is interesting that another article I have read — ‘Harvard and Yale Ascendant: The Legal Education of the Justices from Holmes to Kagan’ — notes how the Supreme Court has become completely dominated by Harvard and Yale graduates without noting the earlier disappearance of public law school educated jurists from the Court.

In its summary, ‘Ideological Voting Applied to the School Desegregation Cases in the Federal Courts of Appeals from the 1960s and 1970s’ did suggest as possibilities for further research:
“Other research possibilities would be comparing justices [judges] who attended public versus private law schools, or elite law schools versus other law schools (Ivy League schools are not the only elite schools).”
I did the first of these and found, to my surprise, that judges who attended public law schools were, by Pearson correlation coefficient, actually a little more conservative than those who attended private law schools, though the difference is almost certainly insignificant. Moreover, those attending elite law schools (the T14 plus Texas and UCLA) show the same result as for public law schools, while those attending nonelite private law schools (private law schools not belonging to the T14) are no more conservative than judges attending public or elite private law schools.

What may explain this result is that, throughout US history, the “public” sector has often been viewed as a coalition of private organisations rather than actually owned by the public as more modern theories would expect. This is most clearly seen in the debates over the nature of primary elections between 1921 and 1944, in which political parties were frequently viewed as private entities with the right to exclude people on any basis they wished. As Hans Hoppe noted in his Democracy: The God That Failed, this is exactly the opposite of modern democratic theory. This influence upon the “public” sector in the US is entirely consistent with the lack of abnormal liberalism in the voting of those judges educated at public law schools. In fact, even on the Supreme Court those judges educated at public law schools were not by any means uniformly more liberal than contemporaries from private law schools. For instance, three of the conservative “Four Horsemen” of the New Deal era — James Clark McReynolds, William Van Devanter and George Sutherland — were educated at public law schools, as was conservative Chief Justice William Howard Taft.

Friday, 2 May 2025

The super-polluter social contrast

In my previous post, I noted how the US states of Wyoming and North Dakota rival the three super-rentier Gulf petromonarchies of Kuwait, Qatar and the United Arab Emirates as “super-polluters”. “Super-polluters” are political entities whose [extraction-based] greenhouse gas emissions per citizen are (roughly) at least 1½ orders of magnitude greater than the global average. Put plainly, citizens of super-polluters profit immensely from runaway global warming, via rents and/or job opportunities unavailable in states without these resources, and via not having to pay taxes.

What is strange when comparing the two sets of “super-polluters is that”:

  1. both groups have a very restricted number of local “citizens”, which accounts for the super-polluter status, but
  2. the Gulf petromonarchies have imported huge amounts of expatriate labour, but foreign labour is remarkably absent from the worst-polluting US states
    • Wyoming and North Dakota have for many decades been amongst the bottom six US states in terms of proportion born outside the country, and this has not changed even with the oil boom and resultant glut that occurred in the 2010s.
    • Moreover, Montana and West Virginia — two other very large polluters — are the very lowest two states by proportion born outside the US
    • Alaska and New Mexico, two other great polluters (both among the most sui generis US states it should be emphasised), have larger proportions born overseas but these are still below to the US mean
In his landmark 2005 Sundown Towns, the late James Löwen noted that North Dakota — the second worst polluting state in the US today — was a sundown state for blacks during minimally the first two-thirds of the twentieth century. Census data from 1970 suggest the only place in the state a black family might live remotely safely was the military town of Minot. The exclusion of blacks in the rural Northwest was in fact so complete as to make research virtually impossible. The same is true of Montana, and marginally less so Wyoming, as can be seen below:
Counties with no or very few black households in 1970 mapped. Taken from https://www.census.gov/library/publications/1973/dec/population-volume-1.html. Note the huge area without black households in the Plains — and note that essentially all the rural Northwest was a sundown area for blacks.
The explanation can, I think, be found in the 2007 thesis ‘Measuring Ancient Inequality’ by Branko Milanovic, Peter H. Lindert and Jeffrey G. Williamson. Although in a revised edition of the thesis that team says it is not likely that any society’s subsistence minimum can be lower than $PPP 300 [1990 US dollars] and that it is possible that in the most exploitative societies a proportion of the population could not afford the subsistence minimum, what is critical is how the team noted the likelihood of lower subsistence minima for tropical and subtropical climates compared to temperate zones. It is likely that in climates as cold as North Dakota’s, requiring extreme shelter, clothing and food, the subsistence minimum would be not merely greater than the $PPP 300 used in their second edition, but significantly greater than the $PPP 400 used by Angus Maddison in The World Economy: Historical Statistics. No society in so cold a climate is analysed and my earlier post aims to explain why finding one is naturally difficult if not impossible. Although the team implies that one needs to be cautious re differences in subsistence minima, it is logical and likely that the subsistence minimum in North Dakota, Wyoming or Montana would exceed $PPP 500 and could reach $PPP 600.

The fact that bosses in Wyoming, Montana or North Dakota must provide workers a substantially higher subsistence income than in the Persian Gulf undoubtedly affects ruling class thought. Whereas in the Persian Gulf the ruling class brings in vast numbers of domestic and other low-skill workers, in the above-mentioned US states this would be too expensive as they require so much protection from frigid weather. Hence, the ruling classes of these cold super-polluters desire to completely exclude undesirable people — most especially and emphatically blacks — to limit the numbers of the lower class they must sustain at the elevated minimum. This, paradoxically, substantially lowers prices for those able to live in these regions below those of many hotter climates. Fewer buyers means less competition, with the result that buyers become more able to exert downward price pressure. This can be seen in how, despite the almost certain high subsistence minima, one’s dollar goes further in North Dakota than in Florida or Arizona.
Purchasing power of $100 in US states compared (2024). The subsistence minimum theory of Milanovic, Williamson and Lindert (2007, 2008) would predict a steady decrease the cooler the climate; however, historic sundown laws and related factors distort this

The basic conclusion is that climate affects the social structure of super-polluting states greatly. Only when subsistence minima are sufficiently low will the wealthy use their wealth to invest in exploitative labour practices: otherwise they are more likely to simply exclude others from it.

Wednesday, 23 April 2025

Super-Republican and super-polluters

I have been familiar for several years with the existence of “super-polluter” petrostates whose per capita extraction-based greenhouse gas emissions are hundred of times the global average. Economically, these “super-polluter” ruling classes who sell the fossil fuels profit from runaway ecological distraction caused by unlimited fossil fuel usages to an extent orders of magnitude larger than the average global ruling class. The wealth of these ruling classes, allows them to dictate policy globally to a very high degree — most especially to prevent demands for ecological justice and even for anything except carte blanche to emit however much greenhouse gases their rulers can profit from. The super-polluters of the Persian Gulf — Kuwait, Qaṭar and the UAE — are well documented by emissions figures. They become especially egregious if we debit zero emissions to expatriates and measure emissions per citizen, a perspective implied correct by Arun Saldanha’s ‘A Date with Destiny: Racial Capitalism and the Beginnings of the Anthropocene’. By such a calculation, Qaṭar’s per-citizen emissions are 450 times(!) the global average, and those of Kuwait and the UAE around seventy times.

The question of whether other super-polluters exists at a more local level has interested me recently. The fifty states of the United States provide a unique opportunity to examine this possibility, because I have long known of statewide breakdowns of fossil fuel production for coal, oil and natural gas, which can be used to approximate state-by state cumulative and present extraction-based greenhouse gas emissions.

Whilst it was too difficult for me to print all the figures, I have shown for each US state details of:
  1. percentage of cumulative US extraction-based emissions
  2. percentage of global cumulative extraction-based emissions
  3. percent of current US population
  4. percent of current US emissions
  5. percent or ratio to total US extraction-based emissions per capita
    1. I have used percent where the ratio is less than one, and ratio if it is greater
  6. percent or ratio to global extraction-based emissions per capita
It might be noted that there are small extraction-based emissions from other sources which I did not calculate for lack of time and unavailability of data. (Extraction-based emissions are not zero for polities producing no fossil fuels currently or cumulatively, which includes a third of US states). Nevertheless, this table should be a clue as to which US state ruling classes are the biggest profiteers from global warming.

I have also shaded “red wall” states in red and “blue wall” states in blue to see how much US political divides relate to actual greenhouse gas emissions.

US Extraction-Based Emissions by State:

State

Percentage of US cumulative emissions
Percentage of global cumulative emissions
Percent of US population (2020s)
Percent of Present US emissions
Percent of or ratio to US per capita emissions
Percent of or ratio to global per capita emissions
Alabama
1.65%
0.36%
1.52%
0.63%
41.526%
1.356784592
Alaska
2.29%
0.50%
0.22%
1.63%
7.463
24.38419474
Arizona
0.31%
0.07%
2.23%
0.00%
0.012%
0.04%
Arkansas
0.46%
0.10%
0.91%
0.47%
51.978%
1.698253119
California
3.59%
0.78%
11.62%
1.08%
9.294%
30.36%
Colorado
2.02%
0.44%
1.76%
3.67%
2.089
6.824671159
Connecticut
   
1.08%
     
Delaware
   
0.31%
     
Florida
0.08%
0.02%
6.89%
0.01%
0.149%
0.49%
Georgia
0.01%
0.00%
3.29%
0.00%
0.000%
0.00%
Hawaii
   
0.43%
     
Idaho
0.05%
0.01%
0.59%
0.00%
0.269%
0.88%
Illinois
4.83%
1.05%
3.74%
1.88%
50.252%
1.641858174
Indiana
1.95%
0.42%
2.04%
1.13%
55.179%
1.802853651
Iowa
0.00%
0.00%
0.96%
0.00%
0.000%
0.00%
Kansas
1.30%
0.28%
0.88%
0.37%
42.098%
1.375445865
Kentucky
6.69%
1.45%
1.35%
1.45%
1.071
3.500860065
Louisiana
5.64%
1.22%
1.35%
3.66%
2.700
8.821153759
Maine
   
0.41%
     
Maryland
0.29%
0.06%
1.85%
0.06%
3.498%
11.43%
Massachusetts
   
2.10%
     
Michigan
0.27%
0.06%
2.99%
0.11%
3.540%
11.57%
Minnesota
   
1.71%
     
Mississippi
0.44%
0.10%
0.87%
0.29%
16.721%
54.63%
Missouri
0.04%
0.01%
1.84%
0.00%
0.220%
0.72%
Montana
1.56%
0.34%
0.34%
1.54%
4.607
15.05241983
Nebraska
0.06%
0.01%
0.59%
0.01%
2.153%
7.03%
Nevada
0.01%
0.00%
0.96%
0.00%
0.184%
0.60%
New Hampshire
   
0.42%
     
New Jersey
   
2.80%
     
New Mexico
2.70%
0.59%
0.63%
7.13%
11.355
37.10152528
New York
0.02%
0.01%
5.85%
0.01%
0.194%
0.63%
North Carolina
   
3.25%
     
North Dakota
1.72%
0.37%
0.23%
5.23%
22.297
72.84921958
Ohio
3.05%
0.66%
3.50%
2.52%
72.055%
2.35423961
Oklahoma
3.52%
0.76%
1.21%
3.69%
3.057
9.987822025
Oregon
0.00%
0.00%
1.26%
0.20%
15.952%
52.12%
Pennsylvania
12.84%
2.78%
3.85%
9.41%
2.441
7.974852848
Rhode Island
   
0.33%
     
South Carolina
   
1.61%
     
South Dakota
0.01%
0.00%
0.27%
0.01%
2.777%
9.07%
Tennessee
0.46%
0.10%
2.13%
0.00%
0.219%
0.71%
Texas
16.23%
3.52%
9.22%
24.74%
2.683
8.767608641
Utah
1.15%
0.25%
1.03%
1.10%
1.070
3.495456591
Vermont
   
0.19%
     
Virginia
1.82%
0.40%
2.60%
0.61%
23.374%
76.37%
Washington
0.07%
0.02%
2.34%
0.00%
0.000%
0.00%
West Virginia
10.05%
2.18%
0.52%
6.81%
13.060
42.66954766
Wisconsin
   
1.76%
     
Wyoming
10.11%
2.19%
0.17%
13.47%
77.804
254.2074428
Federal offshore
2.71%
0.59%
 
7.08%
 
 

The table above shows a remarkable concentration of US greenhouse gas emissions, and a major political divide:

  • Four states account for fifty percent of cumulative US greenhouse gas emissions
  • Five states account for 61 percent of current US greenhouse gas emissions
  • “Red Wall” states have 22 percent of the US population but produce 64 percent of emissions
  • “Blue Wall” states have 34 percent of the population but produce only 9 percent of emissions
    • as noted earlier, this figure is an understatement, but even so the “blue wall” states undoubtedly produce low emissions relative to population — lower than the global average
There is definite evidence of “super-polluter” states in Wyoming and perhaps North Dakota, West Virginia and New Mexico. Wyoming is a definite super-polluter, with per capita emissions 250 times the global average, half that of Qaṭar. It is the least populous US state yet the second-largest greenhouse gas emitter and third-largest cumulative emitter! North Dakota has per capita emissions comparable to Kuwait or the UAE, and West Virginia and New Mexico about half that. Excluding New Mexico, these have constituted Trump’s three best states in all his presidential campaigns, which is extremely telling. New Mexico is a complicated and very much sui generis state, which Trump did not win in any of his three campaigns and did not even trend Republican in 2024. It has a countercultural mountain culture akin to Colorado or New England in its highest lands, politically detached from the pollution-producing northwest and Plains regions. In the other three the political influence of fossil fuels is as hegemonic as in the Gulf oil monarchies, and this is also likely to be true in Texas and Oklahoma. Even more than with the Gulf states globally, the tax-free or low-tax policies of super-polluting US states limit the range of policies possible elsewhere in the country, as business relocation is easier.

Friday, 11 April 2025

An overview of Wikipedia citation statistics

Although I have known of Wikipedia’s citation templates for some time — it is true that when I first made edits there I either did not use them or they had not been created — it is only recently that I have studied them in detail.

What one might call the “big four” — {{cite book}}, {{cite journal}}, {{cite news}}, {{cite web}} — have been familiar to me for some years now, because they can be used directly when adding a citation without copying the blank template from the appropriate linked site below. It is only recently though that I have attempted to look at all the templates in “Citation style 1”, and to see if and where I can use them.

A few days ago, I edited an article on the geography of Antarctica and did not know what to do with publications of the Geological Society of London, and of “Scientific Reports”. Presuming by the title that they must be reports of some sort, and seeing they did not fit the criteria to use {{cite report}} (a template I had used before discussing civil rights politics),  I put them under {{cite tech report}} — a rarely-used template found in only a little over two thousand Wikipedia articles (vis-à-vis over a million for the “big four”).

However, re-reading the template for {{cite tech report}}, it was clear to me that the articles I had cited therewith on Geography of Antarctica did not fit the criteria for {{cite tech report}}. They seemed to be closer to {{cite conference}} or {{cite journal}}, although I know nothing about what conference proceedings are.

The problems I had with this made me both message my brother for some discussion and to actually tabulate the frequencies of the various {{cite...}} templates, which I have done below, alongside percentages of Wikipedia pages used and how the template appears in links (if it does do so).

Frequencies and Appearance in Reference Texts of All Style 1 Wikipedia Templates:

Template # of Wikipedia pages % of Wikipedia pages Template in reference text
{{cite arXiv}} 5,865 0.0099% in link
{{cite AV media}} 61,062 0.10% as |type=
{{cite AV media notes}} 29,630 0.050% as |type=
{{cite bioRxiv}} 415 0.00070% in link
{{cite book}} 1,763,420 3.0%  
{{cite CiteSeerX}} 427 0.00072% in link
{{cite conference}} 19,030 0.032%  
{{cite document}} 1,653 0.0028% as |type=
{{cite encyclopedia}} 219,847 0.37%  
{{cite episode}} 18,233 0.031% as |number=
{{cite interview}} 9,492 0.016% (Interview)
{{cite journal}} 1,094,239 1.9%  
{{cite magazine}} 338,377 0.57%  
{{cite mailing list}} 811 0.0014% (Mailing list)
{{cite map}} 46,609 0.079% (Map)
{{cite medRxiv}} 159 0.00027% in link
{{cite news}} 1,734,008 2.9%  
{{cite newsgroup}} 653 0.0011%  
{{cite podcast}} 5,158 0.0087% (Podcast)
{{cite press release}} 76,594 0.13% (Press release)
{{cite report}} 61,348 0.10% (Report)
{{cite serial}} 279 0.00047%  
{{cite sign}} 833 0.0014% as |medium=
{{cite speech}} 1,426 0.0024% (Speech)
{{cite SSRN}} 557 0.00094% in link
{{cite tech report}} 2,351 0.0040% (Technical report)
{{cite thesis}} 41,638 0.071% (Thesis)
{{cite web}} 5,013,194 8.5%  

Monday, 24 March 2025

Why climate change helps the rich — evidence of a nondoctrinaire kind

Although publications like Red Flag Magazine have long demonstrated that capitalism is entirely incapable by its very nature of ameliorating, let alone solving the climate crisis — and are perfectly effective even with deeply flawed and outdated geopolitical assumptions — Red Flag have now become truly open that the fight to prevent runaway climate change is purely and simply class struggle against the wealthy. In ‘Tropical Cyclone Alfred and the politics of ‘keeping politics out of it’’ and ‘Why Only Socialism Can Save Us from Climate Catastrophe’, alongside articles I could not find or were rewritten, Red Flag demonstrate that climate change is purely and simply class struggle on a global scale.

What is interesting is that Harvard University’s Branko Milanovic, Peter H. Lindert and Jeffrey G. Williamson, so early as 2007 in their thesis ‘Measuring Ancient Inequality’, made a strong implication that the capitalist class does have much to gain from global warming.

‘Measuring Ancient Inequality’ is a study of inequality in preindustrial societies. The critical issue the thesis notes is how the presence of a “subsistence minimum” below which human survival is impossible creates an Inequality Possibility Frontier (abbreviated to IPF) at a Gini index that appears low by modern industrial standards. Hence, in these ancient societies, even if extraction by the ruling class was the maximum possible, it only permitted seemingly modest inequality before the majority could not survive.

Milanovic, Lindert and Williamson use the symbol ε for the proportion of the population belonging to the ruling class, and s for the substance minimum in 1990 US dollars. The initially assumed value for the subsistence minimum is $PPP 400 — a value based upon the work of Angus Maddison in The World Economy: Historical Statistics from 2003.

Discussing their results, Milanovic, Lindert and Williamson note on pages 15 and 16 that:

“If we used Maddison’s subsistence level of $400, then four estimated Ginis would be significantly greater than the maximum Gini (at their level of income) implied by the IPF: three of these are based on data from India, and the fourth is from Nueva España.[The 1752 Old Castille is also slightly above the IPF.] Recalling our definition of the IPF, these four cases can only be explained by one or more of these five possibilities: (i) a portion of the population cannot even afford the subsistence minimum, (ii) the actual ε is much smaller than the assumed ε=0.001, (iii) inequality within the rich classes is very large, (iv) our estimate of inequality is too high, and/or (v) the subsistence minimum is overestimated. We have already analyzed and dismissed the first three possibilities. The fourth possibility is unlikely: since our estimates of inequality are based only on a few classes, they are likely to be biased downwards, not upwards. The last possibility offers the more likely explanation. It could well be that the subsistence minimum was less than $PPP 400 for some societies. In particular, this is likely to be the case for subtropical or tropical regions where calorie, housing and clothing needs are considerably less than those in temperate climates....”

“If the IPF is drawn under the S=$300 assumption, it shifts the frontier upwards enough to encompass at or below it all our estimated inequalities, with the possible (and modest) exceptions of Moghul India and Nueva España.”
If we invert what ‘Measuring Ancient Inequality’ says above about tropical and subtropical societies, we would logically conclude that in genuinely cold climates with extremely high food, shelter and clothing needs, subsistence minima might be substantially greater than $PPP 400. We might also suppose that in the very hottest regions with the most minimal such demands, the subsistence minimum could be still lower than $PPP 300. The initial ‘Measuring Ancient Inequality’ said nothing about how high or low subsistence minima could potentially be. A revised version from 2008, which incudes additional societies, does say it is unlikely that even in the hottest deserts the subsistence minimum could be less than $PPP 300. A 2011 version says:
...violations of the ‘maximum feasible’ definition of the IPF might be due to measurement errors or might reflect the possibility that some people can live below subsistence temporarily. The measurement errors could be of three types: mismeasuring national product per capita, mismeasuring inequality or applying the wrong (too high)  subsistence...[...made more likely by the fact that the extraction ratio is a ratio of two numbers, each calculated with significant amount of uncertainty: Gini, and maximum Gini which depends on estimate of mean income]. In the case of Moghul India and Nueva España, a portion of the population might have been expected to die from hunger, exhaustion due to forced and underpaid labour or lack of elementary shelter. Poor people’s income often does, in any given month, or even year, fall below the minimum and they survive by borrowing or selling their assets. Still, the same individuals cannot, by definition, stay below subsistence for long. The fact that the only two societies in our sample exhibiting a ratio higher than 100%, 1750 Moghul India and 1790 Nueva España, were notoriously exploitative seems consistent with this explanation
If the subsistence minimum were greater than $PPP 400, this would however be difficult to prove. One would need to demonstrate inequality as sufficiently restricted relative to income that a higher requirement becomes exceedingly probable. Even then there always exists the possibility of lesser extraction above a lower minimum. No society in any climate colder than temperate oceanic Western Europe is analysed in ‘Measuring Ancient Inequality’, and partly for reasons I will discuss below, candidates for such are few. [China in 1880 would lie partially within climates likely to have subsistence minima above $PPP 400, but the average subsistence minimum for the whole society would be dominated by the hot southern regions — at least judging by the result of the thesis.]

The above facts acquire deep relevance in light of runaway global warming. Milanovic, Lindert and Williamson imply that a hotter and hotter world will, ipso facto, increase the profits of the capitalists by reducing the absolute minimum wage they are required to provide to workers. Thus, the international capitalist class not merely has zero incentive to ameliorate global warming, but has vast potential gains from making it as bad as possible and permitting lower wages and greater profits. The results also explain the rapid movement in many countries from cooler to hotter regions: capitalist classes were seeking areas where they could gain greater profits, and the lower subsistence minima in hotter regions fit this goal perfectly.

Another fact explained very clearly by ‘Measuring Ancient Inequality’ is why civilisations evolved predominantly in hot deserts. The establishment of a stratified society requires that a surplus be produced, and logically this surplus will initially be small. Thus, it would be critical for the development of a surplus that the society’s subsistence minimum be as low as possible. Hot deserts — especially as they are the most likely region after extremely high mountains to evolve animals with the hierarchical social structures required for domestication — are ideal as the would-be elite is required to give such limited wages. Even more dramatically, the absence of even one origin of civilisation or even of crop agriculture in any latitude beyond the subtropics — European agriculture came via migration from the Middle East — suggests very low subsistence minima were critical for the evolution of stratified societies.